It's an unfortunate fact of life that during
periods of expanded market demand, tenants looking for housing may have to
spend weeks or months in an often vain search for a suitable place to live.
They might end up renting something smaller than they might like, and/or in a
less desirable location. Some have reportedly even resorted to bribes to get
landlords to move them to the top of waiting lists. Meanwhile, they may
double up with relatives, sleep in garages, or use other makeshift living
arrangements.
Rent control refers to laws that set price controls
on residential dwelling units with the stated intention of making life more
affordable for low income renters. They typically function as a price ceiling
on certain classes of residential property, such as flats or apartments, and in
particular areas or suburbs of a city.
Poverty pimps claim rent controls are necessary to
rescue helpless tenants from the high rents charged by "greedy" landlords,
which would otherwise force those unable to afford market rents to leave an
area or downsize to meet their pocketbook. Residential landlords are typically
demonised as bloodsucking rack renters, but these people are rarely
super-wealthy. They're usually small investors who have scrimped and saved to
buy a rental property or two.
According to Harvard University Professor of
Economics, Greg Mankow, some 93 percent of professional economists agree that
rent controls reduce housing supply and housing quality. This is the most
widely accepted position among economists across the ideological spectrum, and
heads Mankow's list of facts upon which professional economists concur. This
near-unanimity is based on the fact that rent controls have proved an abject
failure wherever they have been tried.
Leftists are fundamentally ignorant of basic
economics, have a visceral hatred of free markets, have yet to see a government
programme they don’t like, and evaluate public policy entirely on the basis of
whether or not it makes them feel virtuous.
Their opponents, on the other hand, evaluate public
policy on the basis of whether or not it works.
A free market is neither moral nor immoral. It
simply reflects existing economic reality.
Here's how a housing market works. Like the market
for any other commodity, the price mechanism allocates scarce resources between
competing interests in the most economically efficient manner. Prices send
signals to owners and renters to upsize, downsize, or stay put. House prices
will rise in response to increased demand. And if suppliers are free to respond
to this pent-up demand, they will increase the supply of housing, thus bringing
down prices over time (assuming short-term supply exceeds short-term demand) to
a market equilibrium.
Auckland house prices are a function of supply and
demand for residential housing in that locality. Since everyone apparently
wants to live in Auckland, owner-occupier and landlord pressure on available
housing stock bids up prices, and thus rents. The lead time in bringing
new construction to market creates a short-term lag between increased demand
and increased supply, but over time, developers will respond by building
affordable new housing if government leaves them alone to do so.
Calls for rent controls in the Auckland housing
market are a classic example of how government creates a problem, which then
leads to calls for more government intervention to solve the problem. As we
shall see below, this then creates further problems, which elicit calls for
further government intervention.
On the supply side, the key driver of Auckland
house prices is local government overriding private property rights.
Urban growth boundaries around Auckland and endless restrictions, obstructions,
and bureaucratic delays facing anyone subdividing and building on land within
the boundary prevent the market from responding efficiently to increased
demand.
Urban growth boundaries cause land prices within
the growth boundary to rise, along with the price of everything built on that
land. Unnecessary subdivision and compliance costs increase the cost of new
homebuilding still further. To keep profit margins up, developers will stop
building to the lower end of the market.
Construction of low-priced housing becomes even
more uneconomic in a rent-controlled environment. If homebuilding at the bottom
end of the market is made unprofitable, developers and investors will switch to
constructing office buildings, warehousing, and non-rent controlled housing
where they can generate an appropriate return on investment.
The increased construction of luxury apartments and
houses for the affluent who aren’t affected by rent controls, further harms the
low income earners that the rent controls aimed to assist. The lack of entry
-level new builds exacerbates housing shortages at the bottom of the market,
causing house prices and rents across the board to rise well above what would
prevail if the market were left alone to do its work.
Keeping housing costs down for both owners and
renters means more housing. We need a variety of new supply that accommodates
families at every price point. Rent controls are not the answer. What is
required is a rethink of zoning restrictions, development controls, and
regulatory costs so that developers can bring more low-priced development land
to market.
Instead of identifying big government as the source
of the problem and finding ways to rein it in, leftists call for rent
controls to make housing more affordable at the margin. Having wrecked the
supply side of the housing market, they propose to remedy the market
distortions they have created by doing the same to the demand side.
Rent controls not only exacerbate an existing
supply side housing shortage, but act upon the demand side to reduce housing
quality, deter investment, and raise the price of unaffected rental dwellings.
If rents are kept artificially low, there will be higher demand for low-priced
rental housing and less people willing to supply it at the government-mandated
price ceiling.
If builders and landlords are restricted in the
rents they can charge as well as slapped with high development costs and
lumbered with red tape, they are even less willing to construct more housing.
Residential landlords unable to generate appropriate rates of return will move
their money out of rental property will switch it into more profitable
alternative investments. As in any other market in which demand exceeds supply,
these entirely rational actions create a shortage in the low-priced housing
market.
Landlords holding uneconomic rental properties they
can't unload have no incentive to fix up or maintain, since rates of return are
already lower than alternative forms of investment. Where supply is perpetually
low, landlords don't have to worry about tenants leaving for somewhere better.
They can get away with skimping on maintenance to mitigate the lower rental
income received. If all the rent goes towards paying one's mortgage and other
property outgoings, why bother maintaining the place?
Rent controls create a vested interest class of
protected tenants, meaning they become a political hot potato, and an
untouchable entitlement. Rent controls entrenched in this manner, as in New
York and San Francisco, make rent controlled buildings unsaleable at any price
due to negative returns on investment and decades of deferred
maintenance. Property owners end up walking away, leaving local
authorities to take over ownership in lieu of unpaid rates and taxes.
In these and other cities, the number of abandoned
rent controlled buildings now runs into the thousands, turning whole
neighbourhoods into drug- and crime-ridden slums inhabited by non-rent paying
squatters. This forces government to step in using taxpayers' money for slum
clearance projects. The derelict buildings are then demolished and taxpayers
forced to pay up again for the construction of social housing in their place.
Renters lucky enough to be a dwelling when rent
control are put in place effectively make money at the expense of the
landlord. They almost never leave and why would they? Low income earners
who weren't in a rent-controlled property when the clock struck midnight are
the ones who miss out.
In New York and San Francisco, many people who
started out in rent-controlled accommodation move into their own homes as their
economic fortunes improve. It is not uncommon for a rent-controlled tenant to
move out while retaining the lease in their name, thus preventing the landlord
from legally raising the rent. They will then illegally sublet at a higher
rental to a third party, who is charged a rent well above that paid to the
landlord. This creates an unregulated sub-market in which those desperate to
find a home are trapped.
Rent controls mean that people who wouldn't
normally be renting -- such as young adults still living with their parents, or
elderly people living with relatives -- are encouraged by artificially low
prices to move out and become renters.
Artificially low prices also incentivise others to
seek or continue to occupy larger housing units than they would ordinarily be
living in. When a new family is created, people need more space and are
usually prepared to pay for it. As they age and children leave home, they
require less space. Post-retirement, household incomes typically decline,
throwing accommodation costs into sharper focus.
Rent controls don’t force people to economise.
Under a rent control regime, an elderly couple can afford to occupy a larger
dwelling than they actually need, and have little incentive to sell out or to
rent somewhere smaller. This means families are often unable to find somewhere
suitable to live, causing more scarcity and overcrowding.
Rent rises in a free market are a response to
actual market demand, which incentivises people to make economically
appropriate decisions. Families economise by moving into smaller dwellings to
save money. Childless couples renting or owning three bedroom houses may decide
that they can live in two-bedroom apartments. Families with children who
need the space will move in. Young adults may decide to continue living with
their parent a little longer, until they are earning enough to go flatting.
The net result is that the price mechanism allocates the available rental stock
to those who are prepared to pay the market price for it.
In summary, rent controls do not work. All they
achieve are higher rents and a decreased supply of lower-priced housing than
would prevail in an unregulated rental market. This obliges central government
to step in and build more social housing, thus chaining an ever-increasing
number of people to the state, a sure-fire vote-getter for leftist politicians.
After all, anyone promising to rob Peter to pay Paul can always count on Paul's
vote.
Rent control advocates are either well aware of
this fact and should come clean on their underlying agenda of stealth
socialisation of housing markets, or economic illiterates who need to do a lot
more reading before running their mouths.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Thanks for engaging in the debate!
Because this is a public forum, we will only publish comments that are respectful and do NOT contain links to other sites. We appreciate your cooperation.