Criticism of
the property based rating system has become more intense in recent times, as
rate demands have outstripped the cost of living, wage increases, and
inflation. But criticism of the system
dates back to the 1930s.
The late Sir
Ross Jansen, probably New Zealand’s most experienced and knowledgeable
authority on local government, for a long time advocated for the abolition of
rates, which he described as “antiquated – long past their use-by date – unfair
and unpopular, hurting the elderly and those families on low incomes.”
More recently, in 2003 he said “Between 1945
and 1989 there were five separate commissions of enquiry into local government
funding, all have taken the view that rating is not the appropriate way, but
nothing has been done.” Even the
once-over-lightly Shand report of 2006/07 damned the rating system with faint
praise, but significantly predicted that within ten years it would become
unsustainable – a prophecy then, a reality now.
Even LGNZ –
Local Government NZ – the group representing all the councils of NZ, realised
this, and knowing that they could not continue to increase rate demands ad
infinitum, last year set up a Funding Review working party to “Explore funding
options and alternatives and review funding mechanisms” – but more of this
later.
Change is
long overdue, and inevitable, because the self-evident inequities and
injustices of the rating system are undeniable and many, for instance: -
All
residents are entitled to vote at local government elections, all benefit from
the infrastructure, services, and amenities provided by local government, but only
property owners are taxed to fund it.
By any
definition, rates are a tax, being compulsory, not discretionary, unavoidable,
and imposed by legislation. Making bad
law worse, ratepayers also have to pay GST on rates, in effect, a tax on a
tax!
The impact
on homeowners of this narrowly based discriminatory tax package is further
skewed to the disadvantage of homeowners because all commercial enterprises can
claim back the GST content, and also treat rates as tax-deductible items. Homeowners – who contribute most to rates –
cannot.
Furthermore,
it is based on a property’s Land or Capital value, arrived at by an arbitrary
and questionable procedure that often provides inaccurate results – but worse, not
all property is rateable, so the burden on other property owners is increased.
It impinges
unevenly on individuals, depending on numbers per household. It is harshest on low-income families and the
elderly on low fixed incomes, who face ever-increasing rate demands. Property ownership does not necessarily
equate with ability to pay.
It is a
relatively open-ended source of funds, with little or no control by way of
limits or restrictions on spending. It
encourages “Empire Building” and a “Cost-Plus” system of management, because
councils have the power to set rates at any level required to cover whatever
spending they decide on. This elastic
funding does nothing to impose fiscal discipline, encourage good management, or
promote sound selective procedures to differentiate between spending on
essentials versus other “nice to have” things.
Central
government has devolved many of its responsibilities onto local government, and
facilitated this transfer by increasing councils’ areas of competence, but
without granting them any commensurate financial resources or support as
compensation.
In view of
the above, one would have thought that the existing method of funding would
have featured prominently in the recently published Local Government NZ Funding
Review. It didn’t – apart from being
endorsed by LGNZ by calling for “A diverse set of funding tools . . . with
property rates as a cornerstone”.
Remember, this
review was set up in the first place by LGNZ because it was recognised that
they could not keep on increasing rates ad infinitum, yet indications were that
increased funding would be required in order to finance their future spending
ambitions. The only logical conclusion
that can be drawn is that ratepayers will continue to be weighed down by this
unfair rating system, but will be further burdened by other taxes or levies
imposed on the wider general population.
We foresaw this, and made representations to the working group
advocating that any changes should not be half measures, but rather that the
rating system be changed to a fairer, more universal one.
Of all the
members of the group, only two of the few more independent members replied to
us, and both said that they supported our stance and promised to support
it. They were Auckland Chamber of
Commerce CEO and Local Government Forum Chair Michael Barnett, and Federated
Farmers Manager General Policy Nick Clark – but obviously their voices did not
prevail against the stacked biased membership. Local and central government obviously intend
to continue treating ratepayers as cash cows.
That is one
reason why they continue to ignore this elephant in the room, but there are others. LGNZ wants to retain its open ended funding mechanism
provided by rates, and central government wants to continue to give
preferential treatment to big business enterprises. Many of these are multinationals or internationals,
largely overseas owned, that traditionally have paid next to nothing to directly
support the nationwide infrastructure here within which they operate and make
their profits.
Consider the
actual net cost of rates to any such large enterprise. As a proportion of their gross income, the
cost of rates would amount to very little, especially when compared to the
all-up cost of rates for the average homeowner, calculated as a proportion of
his or her gross income. This great disparity
in real cost and affordability could be interpreted as homeowners having to
subsidise the rates payable by big business.
Despite
propaganda to the contrary, there is a more equitable, affordable, and viable
system that could replace rates – and its implementation would be relatively
easy, simple, and straightforward. To
quote Sir Ross Jansen once more, he said “Taxes should be fair, related to
ability to pay, hard to avoid, and easy to collect”. This suggested alternative ticks all those boxes,
while by comparison the present rating system is demonstrably unfair, unrelated
to ability to pay, and relatively difficult and expensive to collect.
THE
SUGGESTED ALTERNATIVE
Because
local government provides facilities and amenities for every resident and
business entity, a more equitable system would require all to pay their fair
share. Based on statistics for the 2010
year, “Ratesnomore” have calculated that if every resident or business
enterprise were levied by 2.5% of their taxable income by IRD, and these monies
were ring-fenced and used exclusively for funding local councils, property rating
could be abolished.
The
advantages would be many: -
Property
owners – particularly homeowners – would be relieved of an unfair,
discriminatory local tax.
It would be fairer, spreading the funding
burden more widely and thinly, and would ensure that big business paid its fair
share.
It would be easily
affordable by all, costing only a small percentage of taxable income, whereas
narrowly based rates are too expensive for many, property ownership not being a
reliable indication of ability to pay.
It would
obviate the need for government to subsidise rates for low-income people, and
the humiliation they feel having to apply for this.
It would be automatically
inflation proofed.
It would
provide security of income for local government, with sufficient predictability
to allow for forward planning.
It would
require local bodies to exercise budgetary responsibility and tight financial
management, as is the normal requirement for running any other business or
corporate enterprise. It would promote
the necessity to keep spending within the confines of the available allocated funding
– quite the reverse of what happens with rates.
As an income
rather than an asset based tax, it would operate on exactly the same basis as
is used to fund central government, a system that is accepted as fair and
equitable.
Central
government would collect more in tax, and eliminate the disparity in taxation rules
between individual and business taxpayers, as this levy would not be tax
deductible.
It would put
an end to the ridiculous post earthquake situation that existed in Christchurch,
where some property owners were obliged to continue paying rates on homes or
other buildings that had reduced or no services provided, or worse, on
properties that could no longer be occupied or used. Under the present system, that same nonsense
could occur anywhere in New Zealand as a result of a natural disaster.
Having
widely debated this alternative, it seems to meet with general approval and
acceptance. If there were any reservations,
they came mainly from people already involved in local government, revolving
around two issues – the first being that it might threaten local government
autonomy, the second that allocation of funds to individual councils could
present problems, and allow central government to unduly influence allocation
of funds.
It would be
seen clearly as “hands off” if responsibility for the administration and
distribution of these allocations were given to the councils’ own LGNZ
organisation. Legislation could set the
broader guidelines, to be overseen by the Auditor General, but the detailed
work could be left to LGNZ in-house management.
As a suggestion, LGNZ could pay out 50% of the pool to councils on a per
capita (population) basis, a further 45% pro rata to what they received for the
previous year, with the remaining 5% to be paid out more flexibly, on a
compensatory or balancing basis, to meet unique or special needs. Such a method would introduce some
flexibility and year-on-year adjustment in response to any movement in growth,
decline, or need.
The only way
this alternative would adversely affect local government’s autonomy is that it
would remove individual councils’ power to set the level of local
taxation. In all other respects, it
would allow business to proceed as usual, with the added benefit that it would
save councils the considerable administrative expense of collecting rates. They would still be adequately funded, albeit
by a different, but more equitable funding method.
Rick Caddick,
member of Rangiora Grey Power, and spokesman for the Rangiora based Concerned
Ratepayers Group “Ratesnomore”.
2 comments:
I totally agree with the sentiments in this article. In my own case there are three income earners in my house and I am the only one paying local government tax yet they enjoy use of the public transport, having some of their rubbish taken away (general waste is covered by a fee per bag), and other amenities.
A quick calculation shows that my local govt tax would drop by about 40%.
An excellent and succinct article.
It has long been my opinion (and I am sure many others would agree) that a property rates based funding to support local government expenditure is no longer appropriate. As mentioned, the services provided by local bodies are for the benefit of all and therefor should be contributed to by all those who benefit from those services, not just property owners.
We have been set on a course of a "user pay" society for many years now but it appears successive governments chose not to address this anomaly.
Post a Comment